作者:
Thomas Piketty 出版社: Belknap Press: An Imprint of Harvard University Press 原作名: Le capital au XXIe siècle 译者:
Arthur Goldhammer 出版年: 2014-4-15 页数: 704 定价: USD 39.95 装帧: Hardcover ISBN: 9780674430006
What are the grand dynamics that drive the accumulation and distribution of capital? Questions about the long-term evolution of inequality, the concentration of wealth, and the prospects for economic growth lie at the heart of political economy. But satisfactory answers have been hard to find for lack of adequate data and clear guiding theories. In Capital in the Twenty-First C...
What are the grand dynamics that drive the accumulation and distribution of capital? Questions about the long-term evolution of inequality, the concentration of wealth, and the prospects for economic growth lie at the heart of political economy. But satisfactory answers have been hard to find for lack of adequate data and clear guiding theories. In Capital in the Twenty-First Century, Thomas Piketty analyzes a unique collection of data from twenty countries, ranging as far back as the eighteenth century, to uncover key economic and social patterns. His findings will transform debate and set the agenda for the next generation of thought about wealth and inequality.
Piketty shows that modern economic growth and the diffusion of knowledge have allowed us to avoid inequalities on the apocalyptic scale predicted by Karl Marx. But we have not modified the deep structures of capital and inequality as much as we thought in the optimistic decades following World War II. The main driver of inequality—the tendency of returns on capital to exceed the rate of economic growth—today threatens to generate extreme inequalities that stir discontent and undermine democratic values. But economic trends are not acts of God. Political action has curbed dangerous inequalities in the past, Piketty says, and may do so again.
A work of extraordinary ambition, originality, and rigor, Capital in the Twenty-First Century reorients our understanding of economic history and confronts us with sobering lessons for today.
Thomas Piketty (French: [tɔ.ma pi.kɛ.ti]; born 7 May 1971) is a French economist whose work focuses on wealth and income inequality. He is a professor (directeur d'études) at the School for Advanced Studies in the Social Sciences (EHESS), associate chair at the Paris School of Economics and Centennial professor at the International Inequalities Institute, which is part of the L...
Thomas Piketty (French: [tɔ.ma pi.kɛ.ti]; born 7 May 1971) is a French economist whose work focuses on wealth and income inequality. He is a professor (directeur d'études) at the School for Advanced Studies in the Social Sciences (EHESS), associate chair at the Paris School of Economics and Centennial professor at the International Inequalities Institute, which is part of the London School of Economics (LSE).
Acknowledgments
Introduction
I. Income and Capital
1. Income and Output
2. Growth: Illusions and Realities
II. The Dynamics of the Capital/Income Ratio
· · · · · ·
(更多)
Acknowledgments
Introduction
I. Income and Capital
1. Income and Output
2. Growth: Illusions and Realities
II. The Dynamics of the Capital/Income Ratio
3. The Metamorphoses of Capital
4. From Old Europe to the New World
5. The Capital/Income Ratio over the Long Run
6. The Capital–Labor Split in the Twenty-First Century
III. The Structure of Inequality
7. Inequality and Concentration: Preliminary Bearings
8. Two Worlds
9. Inequality of Labor Income
10. Inequality of Capital Ownership
11. Merit and Inheritance in the Long Run
12. Global Inequality of Wealth in the Twenty-First Century
IV. Regulating Capital in the Twenty-First Century
13. A Social State for the Twenty-First Century
14. Rethinking the Progressive Income Tax
15. A Global Tax on Capital
16. The Question of the Public Debt
Conclusion
Notes
Contents in Detail
List of Tables and Illustrations*
Index
* Tables and Illustrations
Tables
Table 1.1. Distribution of world GDP, 2012
Table 2.1. World growth since the Industrial Revolution
Table 2.2. The law of cumulated growth
Table 2.3. Demographic growth since the Industrial Revolution
Table 2.4. Employment by sector in France and the United States, 1800–2012
Table 2.5. Per capita output growth since the Industrial Revolution
Table 3.1. Public wealth and private wealth in France in 2012
Table 5.1. Growth rates and saving rates in rich countries, 1970–2010
Table 5.2. Private saving in rich countries, 1970–2010
Table 5.3. Gross and net saving in rich countries, 1970–2010
Table 5.4. Private and public saving in rich countries, 1970–2010
Table 7.1. Inequality of labor income across time and space
Table 7.2. Inequality of capital ownership across time and space
Table 7.3. Inequality of total income (labor and capital) across time and space
Table 10.1. The composition of Parisian portfolios, 1872–1912
Table 11.1. The age–wealth profile in France, 1820–2010
Table 12.1. The growth rate of top global wealth, 1987–2013
Table 12.2. The return on the capital endowments of US universities, 1980–2010
Illustrations
Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910–2010
Figure I.2. The capital/income ratio in Europe, 1870–2010
Figure 1.1. The distribution of world output, 1700–2012
Figure 1.2. The distribution of world population, 1700–2012
Figure 1.3. Global inequality 1700–2012: divergence then convergence?
Figure 1.4. Exchange rate and purchasing power parity: euro/dollar
Figure 1.5. Exchange rate and purchasing power parity: euro/yuan
Figure 2.1. The growth of world population, 1700–2012
Figure 2.2. The growth rate of world population from Antiquity to 2100
Figure 2.3. The growth rate of per capita output since the Industrial Revolution
Figure 2.4. The growth rate of world per capita output from Antiquity to 2100
Figure 2.5. The growth rate of world output from Antiquity to 2100
Figure 2.6. Inflation since the Industrial Revolution
Figure 3.1. Capital in Britain, 1700–2010
Figure 3.2. Capital in France, 1700–2010
Figure 3.3. Public wealth in Britain, 1700–2010
Figure 3.4. Public wealth in France, 1700–2010
Figure 3.5. Private and public capital in Britain, 1700–2010
Figure 3.6. Private and public capital in France, 1700–2010
Figure 4.1. Capital in Germany, 1870–2010
Figure 4.2. Public wealth in Germany, 1870–2010
Figure 4.3. Private and public capital in Germany, 1870–2010
Figure 4.4. Private and public capital in Europe, 1870–2010
Figure 4.5. National capital in Europe, 1870–2010
Figure 4.6. Capital in the United States, 1770–2010
Figure 4.7. Public wealth in the United States, 1770–2010
Figure 4.8. Private and public capital in the United States, 1770–2010
Figure 4.9. Capital in Canada, 1860–2010
Figure 4.10. Capital and slavery in the United States
Figure 4.11. Capital around 1770–1810: Old and New World
Figure 5.1. Private and public capital: Europe and the United States, 1870–2010
Figure 5.2. National capital in Europe and America, 1870–2010
Figure 5.3. Private capital in rich countries, 1970–2010
Figure 5.4. Private capital measured in years of disposable income
Figure 5.5. Private and public capital in rich countries, 1970–2010
Figure 5.6. Market value and book value of corporations
Figure 5.7. National capital in rich countries, 1970–2010
Figure 5.8. The world capital/income ratio, 1870–2100
Figure 6.1. The capital–labor split in Britain, 1770–2010
Figure 6.2. The capital–labor split in France, 1820–2010
Figure 6.3. The pure return on capital in Britain, 1770–2010
Figure 6.4. The pure rate of return on capital in France, 1820–2010
Figure 6.5. The capital share in rich countries, 1975–2010
Figure 6.6. The profit share in the value added of corporations in France, 1900–2010
Figure 6.7. The share of housing rent in national income in France, 1900–2010
Figure 6.8. The capital share in national income in France, 1900–2010
Figure 8.1. Income inequality in France, 1910–2010
Figure 8.2. The fall of rentiers in France, 1910–2010
Figure 8.3. The composition of top incomes in France in 1932
Figure 8.4. The composition of top incomes in France in 2005
Figure 8.5. Income inequality in the United States, 1910–2010
Figure 8.6. Decomposition of the top decile, United States, 1910–2010
Figure 8.7. High incomes and high wages in the United States, 1910–2010
Figure 8.8. The transformation of the top 1 percent in the United States
Figure 8.9. The composition of top incomes in the United States in 1929
Figure 8.10. The composition of top incomes in the United States, 2007
Figure 9.1. Minimum wage in France and the United States, 1950–2013
Figure 9.2. Income inequality in Anglo-Saxon countries, 1910–2010
Figure 9.3. Income inequality in Continental Europe and Japan, 1910–2010
Figure 9.4. Income inequality in Northern and Southern Europe, 1910–2010
Figure 9.5. The top decile income share in Anglo-Saxon countries, 1910–2010
Figure 9.6. The top decile income share in Continental Europe and Japan, 1910–2010
Figure 9.7. The top decile income share in Europe and the United States, 1900–2010
Figure 9.8. Income inequality in Europe versus the United States, 1900–2010
Figure 9.9. Income inequality in emerging countries, 1910–2010
Figure 10.1. Wealth inequality in France, 1810–2010
Figure 10.2. Wealth inequality in Paris versus France, 1810–2010
Figure 10.3. Wealth inequality in Britain, 1810–2010
Figure 10.4. Wealth inequality in Sweden, 1810–2010
Figure 10.5. Wealth inequality in the United States, 1810–2010
Figure 10.6. Wealth inequality in Europe versus the United States, 1810–2010
Figure 10.7. Return to capital and growth: France, 1820–1913
Figure 10.8. Capital share and saving rate: France, 1820–1913
Figure 10.9. Rate of return versus growth rate at the world level, from Antiquity until 2100
Figure 10.10. After tax rate of return versus growth rate at the world level, from Antiquity until 2100
Figure 10.11. After tax rate of return versus growth rate at the world level, from Antiquity until 2200
Figure 11.1. The annual inheritance flow as a fraction of national income, France, 1820–2010
Figure 11.2. The mortality rate in France, 1820–2100
Figure 11.3. Average age of decedents and inheritors, France, 1820–2100
Figure 11.4. Inheritance flow versus mortality rate, France, 1820–2010
Figure 11.5. The ratio between average wealth at death and average wealth of the living, France, 1820–2010
Figure 11.6. Observed and simulated inheritance flow, France, 1820–2100
Figure 11.7. The share of inherited wealth in total wealth, France, 1850–2100
Figure 11.8. The annual inheritance flow as a fraction of household disposable income, France, 1820–2010
Figure 11.9. The share of inheritance in the total resources (inheritance and work) of cohorts born in 1790–2030
Figure 11.10. The dilemma of Rastignac for cohorts born in 1790–2030
Figure 11.11. Which fraction of a cohort receives in inheritance the equivalent of a lifetime labor income?
Figure 11.12. The inheritance flow in Europe, 1900–2010
Figure 12.1. The world’s billionaires according to Forbes, 1987–2013
Figure 12.2. Billionaires as a fraction of global population and wealth, 1987–2013
Figure 12.3. The share of top wealth fractiles in world wealth, 1987–2013
Figure 12.4. The world capital/income ratio, 1870–2100
Figure 12.5. The distribution of world capital, 1870–2100
Figure 12.6. The net foreign asset position of rich countries
Figure 13.1. Tax revenues in rich countries, 1870–2010
Figure 14.1. Top income tax rates, 1900–2013
Figure 14.2. Top inheritance tax rates, 1900–2013
· · · · · · (收起)
中心发现:“the rate of return on capital outstrips the rate of growth, inherited wealth will always grow faster than earned wealth” (个人财富资本积累速度大于整个社会经济增长,拼死拼活给人打一辈子工都不如老爸有钱厉害) 他认为的解决方法是(最富的人上80%的税收)。 我个人观点...中心发现:“the rate of return on capital outstrips the rate of growth, inherited wealth will always grow faster than earned wealth” (个人财富资本积累速度大于整个社会经济增长,拼死拼活给人打一辈子工都不如老爸有钱厉害) 他认为的解决方法是(最富的人上80%的税收)。 我个人观点是 我认为他的发现非常对 但他的解决方法近乎于痴人说梦(展开)
‘The dynamics of wealth distribution reveal powerful mechanisms pushing alternately toward convergence and divergence. Further more, there is no natural, spontaneous process to prevent destabilizing, ...‘The dynamics of wealth distribution reveal powerful mechanisms pushing alternately toward convergence and divergence. Further more, there is no natural, spontaneous process to prevent destabilizing, inegalitarian forces from prevailing permanently.’ ———宏观来看不平等是经济、社会和政治因素的综合结果,分饼是绝望的,稳定是不可能的,凭借把饼做大能勉强度过微观上的一生。(展开)
提供了一个重要的观点:随着经济的发展,并不存在一个equilibrium of equality,而且市场的力量无法解决这个问题。实际上,市场越完美,r>g这个force of divergence也越强烈。至于最后的政策建议,我觉得太impractical了,也谈不上什么新意。最让人难受的是,这本书太啰嗦了,絮絮叨叨絮絮叨叨简直没法容忍,如果可以重新来过,我直接跳去看conclusion。不值得...提供了一个重要的观点:随着经济的发展,并不存在一个equilibrium of equality,而且市场的力量无法解决这个问题。实际上,市场越完美,r>g这个force of divergence也越强烈。至于最后的政策建议,我觉得太impractical了,也谈不上什么新意。最让人难受的是,这本书太啰嗦了,絮絮叨叨絮絮叨叨简直没法容忍,如果可以重新来过,我直接跳去看conclusion。不值得看全书,更不值得看英文的全书😅😅😅(展开)
《21世纪资本论》在煽动革命吗?它为何让富人害怕? 2014-05-01 ibooks 美国亚马逊上现在最畅销书的是什么,你知道吗?就是这本已经在网上卖脱销的《21世纪资本论》(Capital in the Twenty-FirstCentury)。没办法,右派报纸杂志拼命骂它,克鲁格曼这类自由派连发三篇赞美...
(展开)
Th e principal destabilizing force has to do with the fact that the private rate of return on capital, r, can be signifi cantly higher for long periods of time than the rate of growth of income and output, g. Th e in e qual ity r > g implies that wealth accumulated in the past grows more rapidly than output and wages. Th is in e qual ity expresses a fundamental logical contradiction. Th e en...
2014-11-07 00:371人喜欢
Th e principal destabilizing force has to do with the fact that the private
rate of return on capital, r, can be signifi cantly higher for long periods of time
than the rate of growth of income and output, g.
Th e in e qual ity r > g implies that wealth accumulated in the past grows
more rapidly than output and wages. Th is in e qual ity expresses a fundamental
logical contradiction. Th e entrepreneur inevitably tends to become a rentier,
more and more dominant over those who own nothing but their labor. Once
constituted, capital reproduces itself faster than output increases. Th e past
devours the future.
Th e consequences for the long- term dynamics of the wealth distribution
are potentially terrifying, especially when one adds that the return on capital
varies directly with the size of the initial stake and that the divergence in the
wealth distribution is occurring on a global scale.
2014-06-12 20:20:29 Like Ricardo, Marx based his work on an analysis of the internal logical contradictions of the capitalist system. He 2014-06-14 15:12:47 T is book is based on sources of two main types, which together make it pos-sible to study the historical dynamics of wealth distribution: sources dealing with the in e qual ity and distribution of income, and sources dealing with the distr...
2018-06-11 04:25
2014-06-12 20:20:29
Like Ricardo, Marx based his work on an analysis of the internal logical contradictions of the capitalist system. He
2014-06-14 15:12:47
T is book is based on sources of two main types, which together make it pos-sible to study the historical dynamics of wealth distribution: sources dealing with the in e qual ity and distribution of income, and sources dealing with the distribution of wealth and the relation of wealth to income.
2014-06-16 13:28:03
Over a long period of time, the main force in favor of greater equality has been the dif u-sion of knowledge and skills.
2014-06-25 14:21:11
inf ation was virtually zero from 1815 to 1914, and the interest rate on government bonds was generally around 4–
5 percent; in par tic u lar, it was signif cantly higher than the growth rate. Under such conditions, investing in public debt can be very good business for wealthy people and their heirs
2014-07-13 10:57:02
I want to insist on this point: the key issue is the justif cation of inequali-ties rather than their magnitude as such. T
2014-08-10 18:22:54
In any case, this threat of international divergence owing to a gradual acquisi-tion of the rich countries by China (or by the petroleum exporters’ sovereign wealth funds) seems less credible and dangerous than an oligarchic type of divergence, that is, a pro cess in which the rich countries would come to be owned by their own billionaires or, more generally, in which all countries, including China and the petroleum exporters, would come to be owned more and more by the planet’s billionaires and multimillionaires
2014-08-10 23:21:10
we are living in a time when interna-tional positions are relatively balanced, at least when compared with the colo-nial period, when the rich countries enjoyed a much larger positive position with respect to the rest of the world.54
2014-08-10 23:24:04
T e conclusion is obvious: the net asset position of the rich countries relative to the rest of the world is in fact positive (the rich countries own on average more than the poor countries and not vice versa, which ulti-mately is not very surprising), but this is masked by the fact that the wealthi-est residents of the rich countries are hiding some of their assets in tax havens
2014-08-11 00:42:45
modern redistribution does not consist in transferring income from the rich to the poor, at least not in so explicit a way. It consists rather in f nancing public ser vices and replacement incomes that are more or less equal for everyone, especially in the areas of health, education, and pensions.
2014-08-13 18:12:16
T e overall conclusion of this study is that a market economy based on pri-vate property, if lef to itself, contains powerful forces of convergence, asso-ciated in par tic u lar with the dif usion of knowledge and skills; but it also contains powerful forces of divergence, which are potentially threatening to demo cratic societies and to the values of social justice on which they are based.
2014-08-13 18:12:33
T e principal destabilizing force has to do with the fact that the private rate of return on capital, r, can be signif cantly higher for long periods of time than the rate of growth of income and output, g.
2014-08-13 18:12:54
T e in e qual ity r > g implies that wealth accumulated in the past grows more rapidly than output and wages. T is in
e qual
ity expresses a fundamental logical contradiction. T e entrepreneur inevitably tends to become a rentier, more and more
2014-08-13 18:13:06
dominant over those who own nothing but their labor. Once constituted, capital reproduces itself faster than output increases. T e past devours the future.
2014-08-13 19:43:49
. It is possible, for instance, to spend a great deal of time proving the existence of a pure and true causal relation while forgetting that the question itself is of limited interest.
in 1910, the eve before two world wars, the inequality of capital ownership in Europe reached its highest level in history since industrial revolution. US' total income inequality in 2010 is similar with Europe's in 1910. the extreme concentration of wealth in Europe around 1900 was in fact characteristic of the entire nineteenth century. All available sources agree that these orders of magnit...
2018-04-11 22:40
in 1910, the eve before two world wars, the inequality of capital ownership in Europe reached its highest level in history since industrial revolution. US' total income inequality in 2010 is similar with Europe's in 1910.
the extreme concentration of wealth in Europe around 1900 was in fact characteristic of the entire nineteenth century. All available sources agree that these orders of magnitude--90 percent of wealth for the top decile and ad least 50 percent for the top centile--were also characteristics of tranditional rural societies, whether in Ancian Regime France or eighteenth-century England. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
Inequality of wealth is more tenable than inequality of income because: 1(technically), income from capital accounts for only a small part of national income: perhaps one-forth to one-third, or sometimes a bit more, as in the Ancien Regime Ancien Regime
France: hyperpatrimonial society.
Present US: hypermeritocratic society.
274 the structure of inequality: two worlds
to sum up: the reduction of inequality in France during the the twentieth century is largely explained by the fall of the rentierand the collapse of very high incomes from capital. No gengeralised structural process of inequality compression (and particularly wage inequality compression) seems to have operated over the longrun, contrary to the optimistic predictions of Kuznets's theory. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p277
Currrently, income from capital exceeds income from labor only in the top 0.1 percent of the income istribution. In 1932, the social group was 5 times larger; in the Belle Epoque it was 10 minutes later.
make no mistake: this is a significant change. The top centile occupies a very prominent place in any society. It structures the economic and olitical landscape. This is much less true of the top thousandth. Although this is a matter of degree, it is nevertheless important: there are moments when the quantitative becomes qualitative. The change also explains why the share of income going to the upper centile today is barely higher than the upper centile's share of total wages: income form capital assumes decisive inportance only in the top thousands=th or top ten-thousandth. Its influence in the top centile as a whole is relatively insignificant.引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
from here, it's easy to see Marx' influence on Piketty. Piketty uses the theory of influcence of economic change on societal structure from Marx other than the partisan and majority vote mode in political economy.
p 280
Thus the labor market was totally transformed over the past century, but the structure of wage inequality across the market barely changed over the long run, with " the 9 percent" just below the top and the 50 percent at the bottom still drawing the same shares of income labor over a very considerable period of time. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p306
Goldin and Katz have no doubt that increased wage inequality in the United States is due to a failure to invest sufficiently in higher education.
All signs are that the Scandinavian countries, where wage inequality is more moderate than elswhere, owe this result in large part to the fact that their educational system is relatively egalitarian and inclusive. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p312
The payment of a monthly other than a daily wage was a revolutionary innovation that gradually took hold in all the developed countries during the twentieth century. This innovation was inscribed in law and became a feature of the wage negotiations between workers and employers. The daily wage, whichi had been the norm in the nineteenth century, gradually disappeared. This was a crutial step in the conmstitution of the working class: workers now enjoyed a legal status and received a stable, predictable remunerations for their work. This clearly distinguished them from day laborers and piece workers--the typical employees of the eighteenth and nineteenth century.
Specific investment: the particular functionws and tasks that a firm needs to be performed often require workers to make specific investments in the firm, in the sense that thses investments are of no (or limited) value to other firms: for instance, workers might need to learn specific methods, organizational methods, or skills linked to the firm's production process. If wages can be set unilaterally and changed at any moment by the firm, so that the workers do not know in advance how much they will be paid, then it is highly likely that they will not invest as much in the firms as they should. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p329
Black hole: if noe tries to measure income growth by using household survey data, it is often quite difficult to identify the reported rates of macroeconomic growth: Indian and Chinese incomes are certainly increasing rapidly, but not as rapidly as one would infer from official growth statistics. This paradox-sometimes referrd to as the "black hole" of growth-is obviously problematic. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p 332
the rocketing executive pays and the takeoff of Supermanagers in Anglo-Saxon countries, especially in United States.
On one hand, the specific institutions such as corporate hierarchies and compensation committees play a role in this phenomenon.
on the other hand, technological change, especially information technology may also enhance the inequity of marginal productivity (Li).
Recall that in the 1950s and 1960s the United States was more egalitarian than France, especially in regard to the wage hierarchy, But ih has been this way since 1980, and all signs are that this change in senior management compensation has played a key role in the evolution of wage inequalities around the world.
if we look at various performance indicators, such as sales growth, profits, and so on, we can break down the observed variance as a sum of other variances: variance due to causes external to the firm (such as the general state of the economy, raw material price stocks, variations in the exchange rate, average performance of other firms in the same sector, etc.) plus other "nonexternal" variances. only the latter can be signigicantly affected by the decisions of the firm's managers. if executive pay were determined by marginal productivity, one would expect its variance to have little to do with external variances and to depend solely or primarily on nonexternal variances. In fact, we observe justr the oppisite: it is when sales nad profits increases for external reasons that executive pay rises most rapidly. This is particularly clear in the case of US corporations: Bertrand and Mullainhatan refer to this phenomenon as "pay for luck".引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
more explainatory dynamics behind "pay for luck", rather deduce it as paradoxical.
P355
After World War I, the tax rates on top incomes, profits, and wealth quickly rose to high levels. Since the 1980s, however, as the ideological climate changed dramatically under the influence of financial globalization and heightened competition between states for capital, these same tax rates have falling and in some cases have almost entirely disapperaed.引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p359
the economic model generally used to explain this relative stability of the return on capital at around 4-5 percent (as well as the fact that it never falls below 2-3 percent) is based on the notion of "time preference" in fovor of the present. In other words, economic actors are characterised by a rate of time preference (usually denoted &) that measures how impatient they are and how they take the future into account. For example, if &=5 percent, the actor in question is prepared to sacrifice 105 euros of consumption tomorrow in order to consume an additional 100 euros today. This "theory", like many theoretical models ineconomics, is somewhat tautological (one can always explain any observed behavior by ammusing that the actors involved have preference- or "utility functions" in the jargon of the profession- that lead them to act that way), and its predictive power is radical and implacable. In the case in point, assuming a zero-growth economy, it is not surprising to discover that the rate of return on capital must equal the time preference &. According to this theory, the reason why the return on capital has been historically stable at 4-5 percent is ultimately psychological: since this rate of return reflects the average person's impatience and attitude toward the future, it cannot vary much this level. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p613
Formally, in the standard infinite horizon model, the equilibrium rate of return is given by the formula r=& +y*g (where & is the rate of time preferance and y measures the concavity of the utility function. it is generally estimated that y lies between 1.5 nad 2.5.)引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p363
during the French Revolution, the egalitarian, antiauthoritarian, liberal legislation (which challenged parental authority while affirming that of the new family head, insome cases to the detriment of his spouse) was greeted with considerable optimism, at least by men-- despite being quite radical for the time. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p614
In theory, women enjoyed the same rights as men when it came dividing estates, according to the civil code. But a wife was not free to dispose of her property as she saw fit: this type of asymmetry, in regard to openning and managing bank accounts, selling property, etc., did not totally disappear until the 1970s. In practice, therefore, the new law favored (male) heads of families: young sons acquired the same rights as elder sons, but daughters were left behind. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
Pareto Law or Power Law: there will be a stable inequality.
p453:
it is an illusion that inflation reduces the average return on capital, because the average asset price tends to rise at the same pace as comsumer prices. One can even imagine that inflation tends to improve the relative position of the wealthiest individuals compared to the least wealthy, in that it enhances the importances financial managers and intermediaries, also when size effect is in place. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p479 Modern Redistribution: A logic of rights
Indeed, this is the central tension of any rights-based apprtoach: how far do equal rights extend? Do they simply ganrantee the right to enter into free contract--the quality of the market, which at the time of the french revolution actually seemed quite revolutionary? And if one includes equal rights to an education, to health care, and to a pension, as the twentieth-century social state proposed, should one also include rights to culture, housing, and travel. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
P495
in the modern fiscal state, total tax payments are often close to proportational to individual income, especially in countries where the total is large. This is not surprising: it is impossible to tax half of national income to finance an ambitious program of social entitlements without asking everyone to make a substantial contribution. the logic of universal rights that governed the development of the modern fiscal and social state fits rather well, moreover, with the idea of a proportional or slightly progressive tax.引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
In conclusion, one remarkable thing about this book is that it brings forward the ineuqality of income and wealth through a simple and clear dynamic: r>g; another thing is the unpacking of inequality by using the income or wealth of decibles or centiles other than Gini coefficient, which give a too simple measurement of inequality to interpret.
读一下这本新书 作者说来说去都是在讲美国贫富差距变严重了,有点无趣。从行文来看,知识密度不高,说他能跟资本论pk不太合理,段位差远了。 Th e second conclusion, which is the heart of the book, is that the dynamics of wealth distribution reveal powerful mechanisms pushing alternately toward convergence and divergence. Furthermore, there is no natural, spontaneous pro cess to prevent destabilizing, in...(1回应)
2014-05-04 18:36
读一下这本新书
作者说来说去都是在讲美国贫富差距变严重了,有点无趣。从行文来看,知识密度不高,说他能跟资本论pk不太合理,段位差远了。
Th e second conclusion, which is the heart of the book, is that the dynamics of wealth distribution reveal powerful mechanisms pushing alternately toward convergence and divergence. Furthermore, there is no natural, spontaneous pro cess to prevent destabilizing, inegalitarian forces from prevailing permanently.
p27 coming de cades makes this trend all the more worrisome.
My conclusions are less apocalyptic than those implied by Marx’s principle
of infi nite accumulation and perpetual divergence (since Marx’s theory
implicitly relies on a strict assumption of zero productivity growth over
the long run). In the model I propose, divergence is not perpetual and is
only one of several possible future directions for the distribution of wealth.
But the possibilities are not heartening. Specifi cally, it is important to note
that the fundamental r > g in e qual ity, the main force of divergence in my
theory, has nothing to do with any market imperfection. Quite the contrary:
the more perfect the capital market (in the economist’s sense), the
more likely r is to be greater than g. It is possible to imagine public institutions
and policies that would counter the eff ects of this implacable logic: for
instance, a progressive global tax on capital. But establishing such institutions
and policies would require a considerable degree of international coordination.
It is unfortunately likely that actual responses to the problem— including
various nationalist responses— will in practice be far more modest and less
eff ective.
其实作者是把之前马恩列斯对于帝国主义世界分工的判断用一个简单的模型做了重新的阐述而已。
从资本的回报率和人口红利来分析,还是有道理的
p64
p26
A simple formula backed by a few hundred years of evidence to prove that capital gain is always better than labour income. Actually you don't need to finish the whole book to realize this point. a violent and powerful but impossible to implement law to tax significantly on the rich across the global. The meaning for me is to be a capitalist.
2014-11-30 15:15
A simple formula backed by a few hundred years of evidence to prove that capital gain is always better than labour income.
Actually you don't need to finish the whole book to realize this point.
a violent and powerful but impossible to implement law to tax significantly on the rich across the global.
The meaning for me is to be a capitalist.
@PeterThiel on Piketty someone Quested: What do you think of the economist Thomas Piketty's forecast for greater inequality over the next 50 years as returns to capital compound and the gains are owned by fewer and fewer individuals? Doesn't your monopoly theory of innovation imply this inequality will get worse and worse? PT Answered: Three parts to Piketty: 1 He describes a world of greater...
2015-06-06 18:30
@PeterThiel on Piketty
someone Quested:
What do you think of the economist Thomas Piketty's forecast for greater inequality over the next 50 years as returns to capital compound and the gains are owned by fewer and fewer individuals? Doesn't your monopoly theory of innovation imply this inequality will get worse and worse?
PT Answered:
Three parts to Piketty:
1 He describes a world of greater inequality. I think this is happening and is an important phenomenon.
2 He explains the phenomenon as driven by high returns on capital. I think this explanation is incorrect (the real returns have been negative since 2008, with interest rates at 0% and inflation at 2% in the US).
3 He proposes much higher marginal tax rates and a wealth tax. I think this is very bad policy and almost impossible to implement, and will result in massive distortions as people try to shelter more income and wealth.
I think we need to find ways to grow the overall economy faster -- without faster growth, inequality will be the least of our problems.
2014-06-12 20:20:29 Like Ricardo, Marx based his work on an analysis of the internal logical contradictions of the capitalist system. He 2014-06-14 15:12:47 T is book is based on sources of two main types, which together make it pos-sible to study the historical dynamics of wealth distribution: sources dealing with the in e qual ity and distribution of income, and sources dealing with the distr...
2018-06-11 04:25
2014-06-12 20:20:29
Like Ricardo, Marx based his work on an analysis of the internal logical contradictions of the capitalist system. He
2014-06-14 15:12:47
T is book is based on sources of two main types, which together make it pos-sible to study the historical dynamics of wealth distribution: sources dealing with the in e qual ity and distribution of income, and sources dealing with the distribution of wealth and the relation of wealth to income.
2014-06-16 13:28:03
Over a long period of time, the main force in favor of greater equality has been the dif u-sion of knowledge and skills.
2014-06-25 14:21:11
inf ation was virtually zero from 1815 to 1914, and the interest rate on government bonds was generally around 4–
5 percent; in par tic u lar, it was signif cantly higher than the growth rate. Under such conditions, investing in public debt can be very good business for wealthy people and their heirs
2014-07-13 10:57:02
I want to insist on this point: the key issue is the justif cation of inequali-ties rather than their magnitude as such. T
2014-08-10 18:22:54
In any case, this threat of international divergence owing to a gradual acquisi-tion of the rich countries by China (or by the petroleum exporters’ sovereign wealth funds) seems less credible and dangerous than an oligarchic type of divergence, that is, a pro cess in which the rich countries would come to be owned by their own billionaires or, more generally, in which all countries, including China and the petroleum exporters, would come to be owned more and more by the planet’s billionaires and multimillionaires
2014-08-10 23:21:10
we are living in a time when interna-tional positions are relatively balanced, at least when compared with the colo-nial period, when the rich countries enjoyed a much larger positive position with respect to the rest of the world.54
2014-08-10 23:24:04
T e conclusion is obvious: the net asset position of the rich countries relative to the rest of the world is in fact positive (the rich countries own on average more than the poor countries and not vice versa, which ulti-mately is not very surprising), but this is masked by the fact that the wealthi-est residents of the rich countries are hiding some of their assets in tax havens
2014-08-11 00:42:45
modern redistribution does not consist in transferring income from the rich to the poor, at least not in so explicit a way. It consists rather in f nancing public ser vices and replacement incomes that are more or less equal for everyone, especially in the areas of health, education, and pensions.
2014-08-13 18:12:16
T e overall conclusion of this study is that a market economy based on pri-vate property, if lef to itself, contains powerful forces of convergence, asso-ciated in par tic u lar with the dif usion of knowledge and skills; but it also contains powerful forces of divergence, which are potentially threatening to demo cratic societies and to the values of social justice on which they are based.
2014-08-13 18:12:33
T e principal destabilizing force has to do with the fact that the private rate of return on capital, r, can be signif cantly higher for long periods of time than the rate of growth of income and output, g.
2014-08-13 18:12:54
T e in e qual ity r > g implies that wealth accumulated in the past grows more rapidly than output and wages. T is in
e qual
ity expresses a fundamental logical contradiction. T e entrepreneur inevitably tends to become a rentier, more and more
2014-08-13 18:13:06
dominant over those who own nothing but their labor. Once constituted, capital reproduces itself faster than output increases. T e past devours the future.
2014-08-13 19:43:49
. It is possible, for instance, to spend a great deal of time proving the existence of a pure and true causal relation while forgetting that the question itself is of limited interest.
in 1910, the eve before two world wars, the inequality of capital ownership in Europe reached its highest level in history since industrial revolution. US' total income inequality in 2010 is similar with Europe's in 1910. the extreme concentration of wealth in Europe around 1900 was in fact characteristic of the entire nineteenth century. All available sources agree that these orders of magnit...
2018-04-11 22:40
in 1910, the eve before two world wars, the inequality of capital ownership in Europe reached its highest level in history since industrial revolution. US' total income inequality in 2010 is similar with Europe's in 1910.
the extreme concentration of wealth in Europe around 1900 was in fact characteristic of the entire nineteenth century. All available sources agree that these orders of magnitude--90 percent of wealth for the top decile and ad least 50 percent for the top centile--were also characteristics of tranditional rural societies, whether in Ancian Regime France or eighteenth-century England. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
Inequality of wealth is more tenable than inequality of income because: 1(technically), income from capital accounts for only a small part of national income: perhaps one-forth to one-third, or sometimes a bit more, as in the Ancien Regime Ancien Regime
France: hyperpatrimonial society.
Present US: hypermeritocratic society.
274 the structure of inequality: two worlds
to sum up: the reduction of inequality in France during the the twentieth century is largely explained by the fall of the rentierand the collapse of very high incomes from capital. No gengeralised structural process of inequality compression (and particularly wage inequality compression) seems to have operated over the longrun, contrary to the optimistic predictions of Kuznets's theory. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p277
Currrently, income from capital exceeds income from labor only in the top 0.1 percent of the income istribution. In 1932, the social group was 5 times larger; in the Belle Epoque it was 10 minutes later.
make no mistake: this is a significant change. The top centile occupies a very prominent place in any society. It structures the economic and olitical landscape. This is much less true of the top thousandth. Although this is a matter of degree, it is nevertheless important: there are moments when the quantitative becomes qualitative. The change also explains why the share of income going to the upper centile today is barely higher than the upper centile's share of total wages: income form capital assumes decisive inportance only in the top thousands=th or top ten-thousandth. Its influence in the top centile as a whole is relatively insignificant.引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
from here, it's easy to see Marx' influence on Piketty. Piketty uses the theory of influcence of economic change on societal structure from Marx other than the partisan and majority vote mode in political economy.
p 280
Thus the labor market was totally transformed over the past century, but the structure of wage inequality across the market barely changed over the long run, with " the 9 percent" just below the top and the 50 percent at the bottom still drawing the same shares of income labor over a very considerable period of time. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p306
Goldin and Katz have no doubt that increased wage inequality in the United States is due to a failure to invest sufficiently in higher education.
All signs are that the Scandinavian countries, where wage inequality is more moderate than elswhere, owe this result in large part to the fact that their educational system is relatively egalitarian and inclusive. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p312
The payment of a monthly other than a daily wage was a revolutionary innovation that gradually took hold in all the developed countries during the twentieth century. This innovation was inscribed in law and became a feature of the wage negotiations between workers and employers. The daily wage, whichi had been the norm in the nineteenth century, gradually disappeared. This was a crutial step in the conmstitution of the working class: workers now enjoyed a legal status and received a stable, predictable remunerations for their work. This clearly distinguished them from day laborers and piece workers--the typical employees of the eighteenth and nineteenth century.
Specific investment: the particular functionws and tasks that a firm needs to be performed often require workers to make specific investments in the firm, in the sense that thses investments are of no (or limited) value to other firms: for instance, workers might need to learn specific methods, organizational methods, or skills linked to the firm's production process. If wages can be set unilaterally and changed at any moment by the firm, so that the workers do not know in advance how much they will be paid, then it is highly likely that they will not invest as much in the firms as they should. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p329
Black hole: if noe tries to measure income growth by using household survey data, it is often quite difficult to identify the reported rates of macroeconomic growth: Indian and Chinese incomes are certainly increasing rapidly, but not as rapidly as one would infer from official growth statistics. This paradox-sometimes referrd to as the "black hole" of growth-is obviously problematic. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p 332
the rocketing executive pays and the takeoff of Supermanagers in Anglo-Saxon countries, especially in United States.
On one hand, the specific institutions such as corporate hierarchies and compensation committees play a role in this phenomenon.
on the other hand, technological change, especially information technology may also enhance the inequity of marginal productivity (Li).
Recall that in the 1950s and 1960s the United States was more egalitarian than France, especially in regard to the wage hierarchy, But ih has been this way since 1980, and all signs are that this change in senior management compensation has played a key role in the evolution of wage inequalities around the world.
if we look at various performance indicators, such as sales growth, profits, and so on, we can break down the observed variance as a sum of other variances: variance due to causes external to the firm (such as the general state of the economy, raw material price stocks, variations in the exchange rate, average performance of other firms in the same sector, etc.) plus other "nonexternal" variances. only the latter can be signigicantly affected by the decisions of the firm's managers. if executive pay were determined by marginal productivity, one would expect its variance to have little to do with external variances and to depend solely or primarily on nonexternal variances. In fact, we observe justr the oppisite: it is when sales nad profits increases for external reasons that executive pay rises most rapidly. This is particularly clear in the case of US corporations: Bertrand and Mullainhatan refer to this phenomenon as "pay for luck".引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
more explainatory dynamics behind "pay for luck", rather deduce it as paradoxical.
P355
After World War I, the tax rates on top incomes, profits, and wealth quickly rose to high levels. Since the 1980s, however, as the ideological climate changed dramatically under the influence of financial globalization and heightened competition between states for capital, these same tax rates have falling and in some cases have almost entirely disapperaed.引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p359
the economic model generally used to explain this relative stability of the return on capital at around 4-5 percent (as well as the fact that it never falls below 2-3 percent) is based on the notion of "time preference" in fovor of the present. In other words, economic actors are characterised by a rate of time preference (usually denoted &) that measures how impatient they are and how they take the future into account. For example, if &=5 percent, the actor in question is prepared to sacrifice 105 euros of consumption tomorrow in order to consume an additional 100 euros today. This "theory", like many theoretical models ineconomics, is somewhat tautological (one can always explain any observed behavior by ammusing that the actors involved have preference- or "utility functions" in the jargon of the profession- that lead them to act that way), and its predictive power is radical and implacable. In the case in point, assuming a zero-growth economy, it is not surprising to discover that the rate of return on capital must equal the time preference &. According to this theory, the reason why the return on capital has been historically stable at 4-5 percent is ultimately psychological: since this rate of return reflects the average person's impatience and attitude toward the future, it cannot vary much this level. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p613
Formally, in the standard infinite horizon model, the equilibrium rate of return is given by the formula r=& +y*g (where & is the rate of time preferance and y measures the concavity of the utility function. it is generally estimated that y lies between 1.5 nad 2.5.)引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p363
during the French Revolution, the egalitarian, antiauthoritarian, liberal legislation (which challenged parental authority while affirming that of the new family head, insome cases to the detriment of his spouse) was greeted with considerable optimism, at least by men-- despite being quite radical for the time. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p614
In theory, women enjoyed the same rights as men when it came dividing estates, according to the civil code. But a wife was not free to dispose of her property as she saw fit: this type of asymmetry, in regard to openning and managing bank accounts, selling property, etc., did not totally disappear until the 1970s. In practice, therefore, the new law favored (male) heads of families: young sons acquired the same rights as elder sons, but daughters were left behind. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
Pareto Law or Power Law: there will be a stable inequality.
p453:
it is an illusion that inflation reduces the average return on capital, because the average asset price tends to rise at the same pace as comsumer prices. One can even imagine that inflation tends to improve the relative position of the wealthiest individuals compared to the least wealthy, in that it enhances the importances financial managers and intermediaries, also when size effect is in place. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
p479 Modern Redistribution: A logic of rights
Indeed, this is the central tension of any rights-based apprtoach: how far do equal rights extend? Do they simply ganrantee the right to enter into free contract--the quality of the market, which at the time of the french revolution actually seemed quite revolutionary? And if one includes equal rights to an education, to health care, and to a pension, as the twentieth-century social state proposed, should one also include rights to culture, housing, and travel. 引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
P495
in the modern fiscal state, total tax payments are often close to proportational to individual income, especially in countries where the total is large. This is not surprising: it is impossible to tax half of national income to finance an ambitious program of social entitlements without asking everyone to make a substantial contribution. the logic of universal rights that governed the development of the modern fiscal and social state fits rather well, moreover, with the idea of a proportional or slightly progressive tax.引自 inequality and concentration:preliminary bearing: a mojor innovation the patrimonial middle class
In conclusion, one remarkable thing about this book is that it brings forward the ineuqality of income and wealth through a simple and clear dynamic: r>g; another thing is the unpacking of inequality by using the income or wealth of decibles or centiles other than Gini coefficient, which give a too simple measurement of inequality to interpret.
@PeterThiel on Piketty someone Quested: What do you think of the economist Thomas Piketty's forecast for greater inequality over the next 50 years as returns to capital compound and the gains are owned by fewer and fewer individuals? Doesn't your monopoly theory of innovation imply this inequality will get worse and worse? PT Answered: Three parts to Piketty: 1 He describes a world of greater...
2015-06-06 18:30
@PeterThiel on Piketty
someone Quested:
What do you think of the economist Thomas Piketty's forecast for greater inequality over the next 50 years as returns to capital compound and the gains are owned by fewer and fewer individuals? Doesn't your monopoly theory of innovation imply this inequality will get worse and worse?
PT Answered:
Three parts to Piketty:
1 He describes a world of greater inequality. I think this is happening and is an important phenomenon.
2 He explains the phenomenon as driven by high returns on capital. I think this explanation is incorrect (the real returns have been negative since 2008, with interest rates at 0% and inflation at 2% in the US).
3 He proposes much higher marginal tax rates and a wealth tax. I think this is very bad policy and almost impossible to implement, and will result in massive distortions as people try to shelter more income and wealth.
I think we need to find ways to grow the overall economy faster -- without faster growth, inequality will be the least of our problems.
0 有用 海孩等pk14 2016-02-20
中心发现:“the rate of return on capital outstrips the rate of growth, inherited wealth will always grow faster than earned wealth” (个人财富资本积累速度大于整个社会经济增长,拼死拼活给人打一辈子工都不如老爸有钱厉害) 他认为的解决方法是(最富的人上80%的税收)。 我个人观点... 中心发现:“the rate of return on capital outstrips the rate of growth, inherited wealth will always grow faster than earned wealth” (个人财富资本积累速度大于整个社会经济增长,拼死拼活给人打一辈子工都不如老爸有钱厉害) 他认为的解决方法是(最富的人上80%的税收)。 我个人观点是 我认为他的发现非常对 但他的解决方法近乎于痴人说梦 (展开)
0 有用 松鼠君 2014-07-28
据说是本神书,读来发现是久违的《资本论》风格,统计+基于资本运行的逻辑推演,过分庞杂失之体系,过于纠结不平等的产生却远离试图作为经济学探讨的根基。虽然我也不喜欢经济学与数学过多的纠缠不清,但这无法成为推荐此书的理由。
0 有用 Kdouzi 2014-07-23
大数据时代就应该这么做研究。This year, piketty is the rock star in Economics haha
0 有用 庄常飞 2015-07-07
数据是好的,但1. 过去是否能够说明未来是问题;2. 只看经济不看其他方面是问题;3. 平等是否是目标、平等是否就公平是问题;4. 自己提的解决方案毫无意义是问题。
10 有用 功夫熊猫小碗熊 2014-10-14
历史研究和数据很扎实也很可讨论,但方法和深度上似乎达不到“资本论”这三字所承载的重量,且与马克思/左翼学说关系其实很模糊。皮氏最有雄心说法在于,若无政治社会因素遏制资本回报率高于经济增长率之律,则随着人口增长率和经济总体增长率持续走低,资本收入占国民收入总份额将随时间累进上升,由于资本遗产不断继承和抽取租值而再生产不平等。此条定律欲成立,首先人口总量增长和经济增长率必须足以低到无法改变资本回报率的... 历史研究和数据很扎实也很可讨论,但方法和深度上似乎达不到“资本论”这三字所承载的重量,且与马克思/左翼学说关系其实很模糊。皮氏最有雄心说法在于,若无政治社会因素遏制资本回报率高于经济增长率之律,则随着人口增长率和经济总体增长率持续走低,资本收入占国民收入总份额将随时间累进上升,由于资本遗产不断继承和抽取租值而再生产不平等。此条定律欲成立,首先人口总量增长和经济增长率必须足以低到无法改变资本回报率的累进和摊薄遗产的效应,二是资本回报率高于经济增长率之定律需在理论上有更好证明而非只用数据说明,皆需要深论。对于资本定义亦不清晰,与财富混淆,马氏对于资本在生产流通和追逐利润中产生的社会后果似被皮氏忽略,仅讨论作为存量的资本的生财效应。至于全球资本税设想,似不过将托宾税扩展到资本而已,反无甚新意。 (展开)
0 有用 薄荷绿 2021-04-18
基本讲的是经济学对资本的理解的发展史,作者的核心观点就是资本积累在不加限制的情况下会大于生产的效益,但是他前面铺垫了很多,点有点儿过于细碎了
0 有用 forBrilliance 2021-04-16
松松散散 有些地方隔靴搔痒 分明有很翔实的数据和非常有趣的论证 作者笔力不可啊 再精简1/3 会是一本佳作
0 有用 深海脆脆鲨 2021-02-28
‘The dynamics of wealth distribution reveal powerful mechanisms pushing alternately toward convergence and divergence. Further more, there is no natural, spontaneous process to prevent destabilizing, ... ‘The dynamics of wealth distribution reveal powerful mechanisms pushing alternately toward convergence and divergence. Further more, there is no natural, spontaneous process to prevent destabilizing, inegalitarian forces from prevailing permanently.’ ———宏观来看不平等是经济、社会和政治因素的综合结果,分饼是绝望的,稳定是不可能的,凭借把饼做大能勉强度过微观上的一生。 (展开)
0 有用 雨潇潇April 2021-02-25
Economists must take a stand in public debate. Such admirable courage, and hard work.
0 有用 草野 2021-02-09
提供了一个重要的观点:随着经济的发展,并不存在一个equilibrium of equality,而且市场的力量无法解决这个问题。实际上,市场越完美,r>g这个force of divergence也越强烈。至于最后的政策建议,我觉得太impractical了,也谈不上什么新意。最让人难受的是,这本书太啰嗦了,絮絮叨叨絮絮叨叨简直没法容忍,如果可以重新来过,我直接跳去看conclusion。不值得... 提供了一个重要的观点:随着经济的发展,并不存在一个equilibrium of equality,而且市场的力量无法解决这个问题。实际上,市场越完美,r>g这个force of divergence也越强烈。至于最后的政策建议,我觉得太impractical了,也谈不上什么新意。最让人难受的是,这本书太啰嗦了,絮絮叨叨絮絮叨叨简直没法容忍,如果可以重新来过,我直接跳去看conclusion。不值得看全书,更不值得看英文的全书😅😅😅 (展开)